The more I read about the dynamics of the German economy in
relation to the rest of its Eurozone counterparts, the more it becomes clear
that their ideological differences have extrapolated over time to create a
competitive positioning versus one of co-ordination. Regardless, they find
themselves in a monetary union at a time when the global economy is
“re-evaluating” what works and what doesn’t work, and while this process is
being sorted, slow growth and low inflation is presenting as normal.
Germany has built over time a trade surplus from exporting
more than it imports [along with a few other smaller European economies], while
most of the other larger Eurozone economies have been following the example of
the US economy in running deficits and depending on foreign investments to
grow.
Fast-forward to a post-crisis Europe, and foreign investors
are no longer so eager to hand over their savings, and so we come to the first
opportunity for parity. Germany has an option to draw down its trade surplus
which stems mainly from exports to the rest of the Eurozone by investing in
those same economies it trades with. This will bring Germany in line with the
rest of the major Eurozone economies with running deficits to finance growth
through investment. This is of course a means of buying time to allow domestic
demand in the union to pick-up from the increased spending. Not likely in my
opinion, since there are structural reforms that need to be made in Europe as a
whole to boost competitiveness before investment and subsequent consumption
demand can re-emerge.
This brings us to the other level of parity that can occur
involving the Eurozone. To make Eurozone exports more competitive on the world
market, the Euro needs to further devalue from its current levels. For there to
be some meaningful and lasting effect on exports, parity to the US dollar may
need to be reached in the foreign exchange market with the Euro. At these proposed
levels the trade-weighted value of the Euro should have depreciated enough to
stimulate foreign demand for Eurozone exports. This would also serve an
additional benefit of increasing the prices of Eurozone imports. In short,
inflation would be imported into the union, instead of generated internally.
This would give the European Central Bank (ECB) room to
operate with more conventional monetary policy tools, and put the bank in a
better position to manage long-term inflation expectations. Unfortunately, this
would be at the detriment of the German savers, who would see their surpluses
eroded away by the inflation, while the other major deficit carrying economies
would see their deficits eroded away from getting to pay their debts with money
that’s worth less than the money they initially borrowed.
If the German’s are willing to take one for the team, either
in terms of handing over their hard-earned surpluses directly, or living with
higher prices, and handing over their surpluses indirectly, the Eurozone may be
able to survive its current bout with low growth from a drop-off in foreign investment,
and low inflation [maybe even disinflation] from a drop-off in domestic demand.
If Germany however, fails this test of altruism, then the alternative is
Eurozone deflation, which will further push down wages and demand within the
Eurozone, and leave German without its main export market. This will also push
up the Euro which will make German exports to the world market even less
competitive. At which point a German exit of the monetary union for the sake of
the German economy will become the most politically appealing route.
No comments:
Post a Comment